Memory

Memory
Juel Parvez

Thursday, August 18, 2016

Main challenges facing the labor movement in the RMG sector in Bangladesh


    Bangladesh  is  an  economically  emerging  country  and  these  days  the country  becomes  an important economic potential zone  in  Southeast  Asia. This revolution has started from the nineteenth century  and  until  millennium, due  to  some  political  obstacle,  this  sector  couldn’t  growth expectedly  but after  this  period  it  has  grown  an  astounding  pace  and  remained the sign of Bangladesh’s economy.  However, one of the main streams of that economic development factor is RMG.

   Unfortunately,  RMG  sector  still  could  not  independent  in  their  operation, rather  they  are struggling with several challenges every day and among those labor unrest is one of the key  factors.  Due  to  the  labor  unrest , there  has been  huge  loss  of  production  and  some  of  the factories were ruined by protesters. If we see critically this factor then fixing minimum wages for the labor was the main issue for labor unrest. Obviously, the gap between owner and worker, poor infrastructure, political complexity and many more other factors also can be included for the causes of labor unrest. I will explain some reasons in below.

   Firstly,  Bangladesh  is  a  female  earned  oriented  country,  because nowadays  our  foreign exchange  earnings  are  dependent  on  RMG  and  NGO workers,  and  undoubtedly  it  can  be  said that,  about  90%  employee  of the  RMGs  and  NGOs  are  women.  Despite this fact, there is no proper consideration has been made for women’s wellbeing and, moreover, in any RMG factory they remain simply as a worker without any gender distinction. This drawback never gives them the chance to be an active worker or leader in their organization. 

   Secondly, most of the cases workers did not receive any appointment from factory, so they are being fired from their job without any notice.  I think that is the key reason why workers couldn’t  think  themselves  as  a  part  of  factory members.  So it is a common phenomenon in Bangladesh is that a worker quit their job without noticing their job authority and an employer dismisses a worker without any notice or following any labor law of Bangladesh. 

   Thirdly, being maltreated by owners and midlevel officers, working long hours in a congested room without sufficient rest, lack of recreational opportunity, nutritious foods, medicine, right to legitimate protest against ruthless exploitations, etc. are their daily destiny. Most of the time overtime working hour imposed to them by default and they don’t have any choice to furnish their opinion.

   Fourthly, differing remuneration policy is the key factor for labor movement. Such as, I have witnessed,  there  are  few  garments  situated  in the same place but  those  garments  remuneration policies are  not  same,  rather different from  one  another.  So, people who are receiving small money they always try to shift their job. 

   Fifthly, the organizations who are working for Bangladesh garments labor, has a lack of policy and knowledge.  Moreover,  even  though  garment  sector  is the prime  source  of  Bangladesh economic  development  but  still  there  is no research  center  to  develop  this  sector.  I believe governments need to pay more attention on this sector and need to welcome foreign investors for having a sustainable development of this sector.  

   Finally, there is no respect between workers and owner.  Both sides have mistrust upon one another.  As I mentioned earlier that alike other countries, mostly women are involved in RMG sector, but nobody properly address this that women are not a good protester and mostly they are clam but misguided by man.  It is notable that, it is mandatory to have a proper policy to stop the labor unrest of Bangladesh.


Tuesday, February 8, 2011

GRANTS OR LOANS! DITERMINANTS OF AID COMPOSITION

ABSTRACT

The figures illustrate that it is utmost importance to assess determinants of the grant-loan allocation. In particular, the composition of aid is more informative than aggregate aid allocation since grants and loans are associated with distinct implications. While a grant is a pure gift, loans add to debt stock of the recipient country, potentially generating future debt problems.



For more than fifty years the international development assistance industry has tried to see any alter condition of poor, but, unsurprisingly, the dismal number was constantly same. And this dismal number is drastically increasing day by day. Although successful implementation requires commitment built on stakeholder participation and local ownership, but development procedure emerged very critically- as an industry, as having its own imperatives, as having its own survival at stake, more increasingly, they have begun to understand that persistent poverty makes developing countries vulnerable to security and other threats. Therefore, rhetoric of foreign aid has been increasingly shifted toward the challenges of development. The quantity of foreign aid has hit record levels, exceeding those envisioned in donor promises even with the onset of global economic crisis. But the crucial question of foreign aid allocation remains outstanding. What should be the objective of foreign aid, and which selectivity criteria should be adopted to meet this end? Aid allocation is the vision of millennium development goal, and to meet the Millennium Development Goals, including cutting global poverty in half by 2015, donor countries have been called upon to allocate 0.7 percent of their GNP for official development assistance. But this raises the question of what form the aid should take—loans or grants? Moreover, is there any possibility in grants or loans to reduce poverty? Our experiment will not be far & out of reach, as we will diagnosis it by put some empirical experience and chronological history.

Objectives of the study:
  • To gain in depth understanding of the existing status and conditions of Aid Determination;
  • To capture the present level of aid allocation;

  • To identify the level of awareness of community, including other relevant stakeholders regarding demand and the consequences on poverty;
  • To identify the nature of assistance and their underlying causes, which prominently exists in the project poverty;
  • To get information on the existing Govt. and Non Govt. Agencies ;

  • To examine the current level of aid allocation in the facilities which contribute in poverty reduction, both at loans and grant level;

  • To suggest necessary measures to improve the situation of inadequate level.

Key word: Grants and Loans, Foreign Aid, Donor Country and Recipient Country, Aid Allocation, Development Aid, Debt, Fragile State, Efficiency, Human Development Goal, Conflict, Developing Country.

  • Introduction:
“Our first and foremost word: Aid never runs alone, by both, recipient or donor country; rather it is the mutual commitment for two parties.”
Different developing countries receive different amounts of aid. It is quiet hard to regard this allocation. In the late 1990s, several political and social debate terms heated up on the best form of aid provision. A vivid debate emerged of whether aid should be provided in the form of grants or loans? But the term was super controversial. However, the Meltzer Commission report argues that, poor countries are typically heavily indebted. To avoid a further increase of the debt burden, advocates advise that grants should replace loans for those countries.

After 2000, the grants-versus-loans controversy developed when an influential US Congress Report of the International Financial Institution Advisory Commission (better known as Meltzer Commission) concluded that total cancellation of poor-country debt was essential. One of the conclusions of the Meltzer Commission on reforming the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund was that development assistance should be administered through performance-based grants rather than (concessionary or soft) loans. Under this system, grants would be disbursed not directly to the government, but to a nongovernmental organization (NGO), charity, or private sector business that would offer the cheapest bid for a project. These recommendations were echoed in US President Bush’s proposal in 2001 during the negotiations for the 13th IDA replenishment that 50 per cent of IDA financing to poor countries should take the form of direct grants.

In the post-September 11 world, the perspectives of donor nations on foreign aid or official development assistance (ODA) have changed significantly. Consequently, several prominent observers—ranging from former Vice President Al Gore (2002) to President George W. Bush (2002a), as well as academics, including Joseph Nye, Dean of the Kennedy School of Government, Laura Tyson (2001), Dean of the London Business School, and Richard Sokolsky and Joseph McMillan (2002) of the National Defense University—have called for increased aid and educational assistance to end terrorism. While President George W. Bush refrained from drawing a connection between poverty and terrorism for a time, but on March 22, 2002, he announced in Monterrey, Mexico, “We fight against poverty because hope is an answer to terror.”

As a result of this considerable change, the foreign aid has completely dividend into two groups - donor countries self interest, regarding strategic, political and economical view and on the other hand recipient needs- regarding poverty reduction, improving primary school enrollment, reducing maternal and infant mortality. Consequently, donor countries have begun to mobilize additional resources for the needs of developing countries. Several donors have pledged to reach the United Nation’s target level (0.7 percent of donor’s gross national income) for ODA over the next decade or so, and others have begun to significantly increase their commitments for development assistance (Heller 2005). And our skepticism has been raised from here, debt and debt cancellations are two complementary instruments which, if properly managed, perform better than either loans or grants taken in isolation. Now we will start our journey by the giving definition of Development aid, as it would be clear to understand first part of our hypothesis.
  • Development aid:
Development aid is aid given by governmental and economic agencies to support the economic, social and political development of a developing country. It may be development assistance, international aid, overseas aid or foreign aid. Development aid may come from developed or developing country governments as well as from international organizations such as the World Bank, IMF, OECD or OEEC. It is distinguished from humanitarian aid as being aimed at alleviating poverty in the long term, rather than minimizing poverty for a short term.

  • Principles of aid allocation
One principle which can guide aid allocation decisions is that of ‘poverty-efficiency’ (Collier and Dollar 2001). This can be stated simply: aid should be allocated so as to achieve the largest possible reduction in poverty at the global level.

The principle of poverty-efficiency requires that relatively more aid be allocated to countries with higher levels of poverty. However, it also requires that relatively more aid be given to countries in which the effectiveness of aid at reducing poverty – meaning the amount of poverty reduction achieved per dollar of aid – is higher. Among countries with similar levels of poverty therefore, poverty-efficiency requires that more aid be given to countries in which its effectiveness is relatively high, and less aid be given to countries in which its effectiveness is relatively low.

The appeal of the poverty-efficiency principle lies in its focus on achieving the largest possible reduction in poverty. This matches up well with the view that the over-riding purpose of aid is to eradicate poverty. It is also flexible. It can be applied using measures which reflect the depth or severity, as well as the incidence, of poverty (e.g. the poverty gap), which most observers now accept to be preferable to measures based only on the incidence of poverty (e.g. the poverty head count). It can also be applied to different dimensions of poverty (e.g. mortality or malnutrition as well as $1-a-day or $2-a-day), which is important since the poorest countries in one dimension are not always the poorest countries in another. Also, Adrian Wood (2006) has shown how the principle can be modified to take into account a country’s likely future as well as current level of poverty.

Nevertheless, the poverty-efficiency principle does have its critics. One concern is that its strict application would cause donors to neglect poor countries in which aid effectiveness is considered to be very low: difficult partnerships or fragile states, for example. An approach not subject to this problem would be to allocate aid so as to achieve, or get as close as possible to achieving, a similar reduction in poverty in all countries. However, such an approach would deviate from the poverty-efficiency principle, and therefore come at the cost of a smaller reduction in poverty at the global level.

A different concern is that poverty-efficiency fails to take into account the ‘unjust’ disadvantages that some developing countries face. Examples include location in the tropics and being land-locked, which tend to lower countries’ growth rates but are outside the control of government policy. An alternative approach which would take these factors into account is an ‘equal-opportunity’ aid allocation, proposed by Llavador and Roemer (2001). This would allocate aid so as to compensate countries in which high levels of poverty, or slow rates of poverty reduction, are the result of unjust disadvantages, but not those in which government actions are more responsible.

Which of these different principles – poverty-efficiency, country-by-country targets, or equal-opportunity – is right is of course a normative question involving philosophical and moral considerations. It is, however, a question certainly worth thinking more about, not least to see how much consensus exists on which principle is considered to be right.

The consequence of this paper will come as follows. We first review critically a few of the arguments weighting grants against lending to the poorest countries, notably the incentive effects of each instrument. We then address what we regard as the most serious criticism against loans, namely the issue of ‘defensive lending’. If lenders had to refinance by themselves their loans to the poorest countries, then it is clear that the instrument is equivalent to a grant. We show econometrically that this has not been the case in general. Defensive lending is an occasional, not a systematic feature, of loans to the poorest countries.



  • Depth of Hypothesis
1. Efficiency

Does grants are more effective than loans in fighting poverty? So many arguments have existed in several articles, including Google search, but no result we have found to write down, almost in every case the result was skeptical. The Grants versus Loans debate is concerned with a comparison between ODA instruments. This is not how the OECD Development Assistance Committee (DAC) defines ODA, and that very fact may well contribute to explaining why there ever was a debate between loans and grants. Instead of counting ODA as the actual budgetary cost for donor countries, the DAC defines it as the sum of grants and concessional loans (i.e. loans carrying an element of subsidization ). Nunnenkamp, Thiele and Wilfer (2005/2007) conduct a simple correlation analysis to explore whether loans and grants have different impacts on economic growth. They look, on the one hand, at the relation between total net ODA, total net loans, total grants and the grant element in ODA commitments (computed as the product of the grant element as defined in DAC statistics and ODA commitments), and, on the other, average per capita growth in gross national income over the subsequent five years. Their analysis finds no substantial difference in the impact on economic growth between ODA distributed through grants and ODA distributed through loans.

 
Secondly, it may think that ODA always relates with local fiscal discipline. Various studies shows that grants and loans are associated with distinct growth effects. While grant is a pure gift, it is need not to be repaid, so critics fear that it can do entail a potential disincentive on the mobilization of public revenues and on the quality of public spending. Increased dependency on external aid may result. On the other hand, loan is not a gift, it has to be repaid. So it has own responsibility. It could be help build financial discipline and promote the efficient use of funds. To arise from this problem Daniel Cohen, Pierre Jacquet, and Helmut Reisen suggested for dynamic operation, like they tried to get the answer first- in which beneficiary countries rely on the continuation of grants and in which development institutions are keen on producing a given level of ODA. Final they come to upon the answer- ‘grant pushing’ behavior by development institutions might again weaken that incentive.

 
Odedokun (2003), using yearly panel data from 1970 to 1999 for 72 ODA beneficiaries, finds that concessional loans are typically associated with higher fiscal revenues, lower public consumption, higher investment rates and lower dependency of the public deficit on external financing. In poor countries, a higher level of grants in total ODA is associated with a lower tax effort. Gupta et al. (2004) look at a set of 107 countries that benefited from ODA between 1970 and 2000, assessing the impact of grants and loans on the domestic fiscal effort. They find that an increase in total ODA (sum of grants and concessional loans) leads to a decline in fiscal receipts in the beneficiary country.
In summary, the argument according to which loans are equivalent to grants is not warranted from these analyses, at least from the point of view of the incentives that each instrument carries.

2. Aid composition matters

Aid composition is matter, as there has several points of view, what we’ve asserted in the first in this article. From the point of view of efficient aid, each of the “big three” donors- US, Japan, and France- has a different distortion: the US has targeted about one-third of its total assistance to Egypt and Israel; France has given overwhelmingly to its former colonies; and Japan’s aid highly correlated with UN voting partners. These countries’ aid allocation may be very effective at promoting strategic interest, but not the actual form of loans or grants and the result is that bilateral aid has only a weak association with poverty, democracy, and good policy. Practically, richer countries have more reasons than ever to address this new world disorder. But the record has been uneven, to say the least. The world power has helped to create a failed state, for a variety of self-interested motives, contributing to even greater global insecurity. The aid supposed to support Iraqi reconstruction has been mired in distortions designed to maximize the benefits for US companies. Elsewhere, donors have been inconstant partners. Many of the most fragile countries receive little assistance. Just as with all developing countries, donors have many criteria for allocating—or not allocating—aid. So regarding again to Collier and Dollar 2001, what we’ve mentioned before, while they tried to shows- more aid to be allocate to countries with higher levels of poverty, but by showing Alesina & David report, what could bring answer for “big three”?
In other mind, the revenue performance of developing countries in the past decade has been disappointing. Although country experiences have varied, tax revenue in the poorest developing countries and regions has, in most cases, been stagnant or has declined. What happens when a country’s financial aid is increased, and is the effect different if the aid takes the form of grants or of loans? We distinguished between the effects of loans and grants on revenues, holding constant other variables that have a bearing on a country’s ability to raise taxes (including per capita income, shares of agriculture and industry in the country’s GDP, and a ratio of a sum of imports and exports to its GDP). And merely effect different if the aid takes the form of grants. Rather, again, it depends on country’s local policy, efficiency, per head income, birth & mortality rates, and consciousness, as we said before; fragile states are merely paying tax, that is why they are poor and so it should not be comparable with grants or loans.

The relationship between revenues and foreign aid is fraught with difficulties. Foreign aid may respond to shortfalls in domestic revenue mobilization, suggesting that the causation may run from revenues to foreign aid, rather than vice versa. Benedict Clements, Sanjeev Gupta, Alexander Pivovarsky, and Erwin R. Tiongson, addressed this issue in the empirical results by checking how the results differ when statistical techniques are used that correct for any simultaneous causality (that is, endogeneity) between aid and revenues.

The empirical results suggest that an increase in overall aid (net loans plus grants) causes a country’s domestic revenues to decline, although the separate effects of its two components are different. An increase in loans causes government revenues to increase, whereas an increase in grants causes revenues to decline. Thus, if the loan amount were increased from an average of 1.5 percent of GDP to, for example, twice that level, revenue would increase by 0.35 percentage points of GDP. If grants were doubled from an average of 4 percent of GDP, revenue would fall by about 1.1 percent of GDP. This implies that for each additional dollar in aid in the form of grants, 28 percent is offset by lower domestic revenues. The doubling of grants from the sample average would also increase a country’s dependence on aid because the ratio of grants to domestic revenues would rise from 18 percent to 39 percent.
  • Why the proposed shift of aid from loans to grants?
Some recent initiatives have called for a shifting of foreign aid toward grants while increasing overall assistance to developing countries. These initiatives are driven, in part, by the belief that excessive lending has led to massive debt accumulation in many developing countries and has not helped them reach their development objectives. In response to these initiatives, some donor countries and researchers have expressed concern that a significant shift to grants would make it difficult for the International Development Association, the World Bank’s concessional lending arm, to maintain lending at the existing level.
Lerrick and Meltzer (2002) as well as Radelet (2005) argue that loans carry perverse incentives, in particular linked to the pressures on creditors to make new loans to allow countries to repay old ones, whereas grants can be devised to generate positive incentives. Contrary to loans, grants do not contribute to the debt overhang.
However, the core meaning of this above shifting is very clear, humanitarian aid for poor country. But the question has remained on this shifting, is it the actually shifted for poor people rights? Or are there has some another reason? Today we are living very complicated world, where the system is very easy and naive, but the management is super critical.

The Grants VS Loans are very critical and complex subject. Whether, the term has very highlighted after 2000, especially post 911. And before 2000, there are so many articles has been published that, “large portion of foreign aid flowing developed to developing countries is wasted and only increase unproductive public consumption”. But after having all of those words, there has been a big change in foreign aid industry….that is transformation from loans to grants. So ultimately the question can be rise that, do developed countries respond to the economically correct incentives in giving foreign aid? Or, instead, is the pattern of aid flows dictated by political and strategic considerations which have little to do with rewarding good policies and helping the more efficient and lees corrupt regimes in developing countries?

Strong powers used to fear each other. Now their concerns emanate from states that are fragile and which threaten global stability. These states are still numerous; by most definitions, at least one-third of all developing countries. And they harbor up to 1.5 billion people, almost a quarter of the world. Poor institutional development, corruption, inefficiencies and bureaucratic failures in those developing countries are often cited as reasons for these results. Fragile states are of universal concern because they are the source of many of the most challenging global problems. Many are chronically prone to conflict—with more than a dozen civil wars raging at any one time. Some are major exporters of narcotic drugs (Afghanistan, Burma, Colombia) and some are developing nuclear weapons and exporting the capability to develop them (North Korea and Pakistan). They are incubators of violence and terrorism, such as Afghanistan under the Taliban regime and Somalia today. In the zones of death, people are displaced, property is destroyed and natural resources are plundered. So the question is going to loom large, as one third population of the world are poor and maximum states of them are frequently going under military law, so is foreign aid has been used to foster the process of democratization or not?

Alberto Alesina, David Dollar shows a data from Development Assistance Committee of the OECD, while they have converted the flows into constant 1985 dollars and for much of their analysis average these for five year periods beginnings with 1970-74 and ending with 1990-94. They have shown that, 70% of the total accounted for by four countries: US, Japan, France, and Germany. Even they have also shown in their article is that, their (donor country) have very creative politics while they deal for multi or bilateral aid. Sometimes each country has each own interest. Such as UN voting system, while there are deeply relation between voter country and leading country, its call UN friend.

There are so many witness can be providing favor of actual interest of foreign aid. Probably it can be question here that, why we are arguing about foreign aid, candidly can be provide answer that, the meaning of transformation from loans to grants is not new idea. Rather it is a continual process of foreign aid industry. By giving that illustration we can catch some ethnical character of foreign aid industry and what is the answer for transform. As we’ve mentioned before that, the shifting term derive a question whether it could be more efficient or not for recipient country and it is also may worry that, such a shift could dampen public support in donor countries for transfers to developing countries.

In contrast, grants are viewed as free resources and could therefore substitute for domestic revenues. The strength of these arguments depends on how strongly policymakers perceive loans, in practice, as being different from grants. If a large share of these loans is provided on highly concessional terms, and loans are frequently forgiven, policymakers may come to view them, over time, as roughly equivalent to grants.

However, finally it could be say that, the main fact for shifting was not a humanitarian answer, rather it implies to pull of terror form the world, or it could be way of another political interest what we are not arguing in this article.
  • Conclusion: beyond grants versus loans, towards modern development finance
How donors meet the challenges of fragile and failing states provides the acid test for aid. While most aid has been a vehicle for donors to build relationships with individual developing countries, the predicament of the fragile states presents two outstanding justifications for activism. One is obviously humanitarian, since development failure has continued to impoverish the lives of many hundreds of millions of people. The other is self-interest, given the dangers posed by the fragile states to global security and health.

The basic message of our paper is that the grants-versus-loans debate as it was cast during the IDA13 replenishment has been misleading and largely irrelevant. It came in a context where most multilateral and, even more, bilateral ODA was already delivered as outright grants. It broadly disregarded financial and economic analysis and reached one sided conclusions that do not fit well with empirical observations. By putting the focus on ODA instruments, however, it has helped to raise awareness about the link between such instruments and aid effectiveness. Our main conclusion is that there is a rationale for loans as effective ODA delivery mechanisms and that there is also a rationale for development institutions to provide concessional loans.

A further reason for limited aid effectiveness may be that, donors are not only led by altruistic motives but also pursues economic and political interests when giving aid. Modern ODA should build on the capacity of donors to use a wide range of financial instruments, from direct subsidies to market loans, guarantees, and state contingent debt. The key and the originality, therefore, lie in mixing taxpayers’ money with a number of financial instruments, in a flexible and innovative manner. This is, of course, a major departure from the conventional conception of ODA instruments as either direct grants or concessional loans.

The obstacle of our conclusion goes beyond of grant VS loan. While after IDA13, the terms of aid has little bit changed. From then, the maximum portion of grants, for example, has been received not only by governments rather by the particular NGOs also and while NGOs doesn’t have any complexity by the fiscal revenues and public consumption, so spontaneously a question can derive, why the ambition was not succeed? Its probably raise the question what is the actual reason for shifting grants after 2000, and how the actors are acting throw maintaining the commands of political governance. At first, we have mentioned that- Aid never runs alone, by both, recipient or donor country; rather it is the mutual commitment for two parties- the mean of this word is, the success will never come until mutual commitment between donor and recipient country. Today donor country try to reduce the poverty by diminishing terror from the world throw giving grants, but we should not forget that poverty is not occurred from terror, so our foremost wants should be reduce the poverty and when we will achieve it then automatically the other problem will cure. But today our word definition has been changed. We need to rethink again. So, a question frequently murmurs to our ear, despite of good intention why development assistance has failed?

Sunday, October 31, 2010

About Lee Myung-bak

South Korean President Lee Myung-bak took up office in February 2008, after having scored a record victory margin in December's presidential election with his "Economy, First!" pledge.


Previously the CEO of Hyundai Construction and a former mayor of Seoul, Mr Lee is nicknamed "The Bulldozer" for his forcefulness. He has promised to boost growth, cut high youth unemployment and raise competitiveness in the face of challenges from China and Japan. His Grand National Party won control of parliament in elections in April 2008, which observers predicted would allow him to push through his economic reforms. However, his approval ratings plummeted after he agreed to resume US beef imports in order to secure a free trade deal.

He was forced to apologise for failing to heed public concerns, and the domestic crisis sparked by the row over US beef imports is thought to have reduced his chances of implementing other promised reforms. In the autumn of 2008, Mr Lee warned that the South Korean economy could be even more badly affected by the global credit crisis than it was by the Asian financial crisis of the late 1990s.

Lee Myung-bak is the country's first president with a business background. He entered politics in 1992 and became mayor of Seoul in 2002. Mr. Lee has expressed willingness to meet North Korean leader Kim Jong-Il whenever necessary and has described his attitude to inter-Korean relations as "pragmatic, not ideological". He has pledged to take a tougher line with Pyongyang than his predecessor, Roh Moo-hyun.
As we have mentioned before that President Lee Myung-bak is former CEO of Hyundai Construction and his nick name is "The Bulldozer”, so easily we can assume that President Lee Myung-bak has strict behavior. As Lee stated that he wanted to restore better relations with the United States through a greater emphasis on free market solutions, but two months after his inauguration, Lee’s approval ratings stood at 28% and by June 2008 they had reached 17%.Then U.S.-korea Free Trade Agreement or KORUS FTA, which faces opposition from legislators in both countries. While it was expected that Lee’s agreement during the summit to partiality lift the ban on U.S. beef imports would remove the obstacles in approving the KORUS FTA in the U.S. Many Korean protested the resumption of U.S. beef imports. In the mean time the Korean government issued a statement warning that violent protesters would be punished and measures would be taken to stop clashes between police and protesters. All of South Korea’s former presidents, including Kim Young-sam, Kim Dae-jung and Roh Moo-hyun, saw a decrease in popularity at the end of their respective tenures. But in the early stages of their presidential terms they were powerful leaders, earning approval of over 70 percent each.

Under the Lee myung-bak administration, police are reportedly moving to restrict assemblies and demonstrations depending on their purposes as well as imposing fines on people who refuse on the street demands to present identification. Lee has been called “authoritarian,” “pro-big business and anti labor”. Lee vowed in 2007 to “get rid of” political and “hard line” unions. Amnesty International highly criticized the human rights violation caused by the presidency of Lee Myung-bak. Not only political freedoms but also Lee tried to interfere on press freedoms. The chief executives of Korea Broadcastings Advertising Corporation and the English broadcasting company, Arirang TV have been replaced by government supporters. It has also been suggested that is trying to change the top executive of KBS (Korean Broadcasting System), the country’s most powerful television network.

However I don’t want to criticize of President Lee Myung-bak, as I am trying to find out the actual ideology or political view of President Lee Myung-bak. Although I’ve already discussed about his some recent activities but still we have some remain. If we say that President Lee Myung-bak is doing liberal minded presidency then it will be right? Our conclusion says that Lee’s Political Background is from Grand National Party and that political view is conservatism which we could see on Lee’s presidency. But the Grand National Party also liberal conservatism but which we haven’t seen Lee’s presidency. Actually I think that President Lee’s presidency is so strict and conservative. According to the rule of “pro big business and anti labor” we can say that Lee’s presidency implying to “the rich get richer and the poor get poorer” (부익부빈익빈).
It may prospective advantages for a country when the peoples of country follow their president. But in Korea we have seen for several times that people are doing demonstrate against the president. Although that doesn’t mean that President Lee Myung-bak is going to wrong way. Because as we’ve mentioned before that President Lee Myung-bak has promised to push through economic reforms, so this kind of prospective idea can give a good achievement for Korea and as Lee’s presidency has forced for 3 years; so still we have to see for remaining 2 years to do comments on his presidency. If we analyze to presidency of Lee’s first year then we can say that he is going to follow the presidency rule of Park Chung-hee

JP

Monday, August 16, 2010

Demanding for a good governance

The Problem with Presidents



We need global, not just national, leaders.

Mao Zedong was right. we should always focus on the primary, not secondary, contradictions. And right now, our primary global contradiction is painfully obvious: the biggest challenges of governance are global in origin, but all the politics that respond to them are local. There are many wise leaders around the world, but there is not enough global leadership.




The first decade of the 21st century has only accelerated the emergence of such challenges. The era began with 9/11, when a plot hatched in Afghanistan brought down the Twin Towers in Manhattan. In 2003 SARS jumped simultaneously from a village in China to two cities on opposite sides of the world—Singapore and Toronto. Barely six years later, H1N1 haunted the globe. The speed and ferocity of the Lehman Brothers crisis brought the world to the brink of a meltdown.



The biggest challenge of all is progressing more slowly than the financial crisis. But climate change is the perfect example of just how ineffective our current leadership structures are. The solution to global warming is quite simple: we have to increase the economic price of greenhouse-gas emissions equitably, with rich countries paying more and poorer nations paying less, but with all countries paying some price. Yet someone has to make the first move. America—whose population is only 5 percent of the world but consumes 25 percent of the world’s gasoline—is the obvious candidate. If the price of a gallon of gasoline in the United States were to be raised by $1 (and that would still make an American gallon cheaper than a European or Singaporean gallon), the change in driving habits would dramatically cut greenhouse-gas emissions. And American leadership, by example, would likely change attitudes in other nations.

In many ways, the United States is the wisest country in the world. It certainly remains the most successful, despite its recent travails. Yet in this land of wisdom and success, not one American politician would dare advocate a $1 solution to save the world. It would mean immediate political suicide. Herein lies the nub of the problem. Politicians are elected in local constituencies to take care of local concerns. Those who try to save the world will not last long.




This is why humanity needs a wake-up call. We can develop good domestic governance, from New Zealand to the Netherlands, from Singapore to Sweden. But good national leaders can only mitigate the shocks of global challenges, not solve them. Solutions have to be tackled through global organizations like the United Nations and the International Monetary Fund, or global coalitions like the G20.



In theory, everyone agrees that we need to strengthen and open up these institutions. In practice, however, global organizations and coalitions are controlled by a few powerful national governments that put their national interests ahead of the world’s. This is the ultimate global paradox. Great powers want to use their status to dominate global organizations—think of how the United States and Europe still split the leadership of the World Bank and the IMF. But the more they control and distort the agenda of those institutions, the more they weaken them. And if these organizations are weak, solutions to global problems will simply not emerge.



The only way around this is to develop a strong, new international consensus, among citizens as well as governments, that the world needs more global governance (not global government). Only then will the mightiest nations think of the greater good and allow institutions—from the G20 to the U.N., from the IMF to the World Trade Organization—to be revitalized. Yes, these bodies are imperfect. But in the world of politics, it is easier to reform existing institutions than to create perfect new ones. Mao’s successor, Deng Xiaoping, taught us how pragmatism could revive one great civilization. We need to muster the same pragmatism to save humanity.




Mahbubani, dean of the Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy at the National University of Singapore, is the author of The New Asian Hemisphere: The Irresistible Shift of Global Power to the East.

Monday, May 3, 2010

유누스와 아디다스, 저가 신발 제작에 합의

지난 3월 21일 노벨평화상 수상자 무하마드 유누스 총재가 이끄는 그라민 그룹과 독일의 스포츠 기업 아디다스가 방글라데시의 가난한 사람들을 위해 저가 신발을 만드는데 힘을 모으기로 합의했다. 양측은 양해각서(MOU)를 체결한 후 연말까지 시제품을 내놓기로 했다고 방글라데시의 유력 일간지 The Daily Star지가 유누스 센터의 말을 인용해 보도했다.





ⓒ Grameen Guest/Flickr

유누스 총재는 “이 신발의 가격은 가난한 사람들도 구입할 수 있는 수준이 될 것이다. 그리고 가난한 사람들을 질병으로부터 보호해 줄 것이다”라고 말했다. 그라민그룹과 아디다스의 목표는 어른 아이 할 것 없이 모두가 신발을 신게 하는 것이다. 특히 시골의 어린이들이 맨발로 걸어 다니면서 질병을 옮기는 일을 예방하는데 큰 도움이 될 것으로 보인다.


이번 일은 유누스에게도 중요한 업적이 될 것이다. 이전에도 그라민그룹은 프랑스 기업 Danone, Veolia와 함께 가난한 사람들에게 영양과 안전한 식수를 제공하기 위한 사회사업을 시행하기도 했다. 또한 독일의 BASF와 미국의 인텔도 그라민 그룹과 함께 가난한 사람들에게 모기 퇴치와 정보 및 의사소통 기술을 제공하는 사회사업에 협력했었다(기후변화행동연구소 이승민 객원연구원).

Tuesday, April 27, 2010